Opinion: Following the money

The city council recently approved pay raises for Boulder’s city manager and attorney. They both received “equity” raises, apparently to bring them up to comparable levels with others in similar positions. They also received “very high” performance ratings and 4 percent permanent “performance” salary increases. The totals were a 9 percent increase for the manager, to $236,508, and a 5 percent increase for the attorney, to $203,839. Does the council really think that the city’s performance was that great? And why were these not just bonuses, so as to leave room for future flexibility? Besides, matching other cities’ salaries, and then raising them, will unnecessarily escalate all salaries when others cities follow suit.
The 2014 Boulder Transportation Master Plan shows a very significant funding gap between expected revenues and what is needed to reduce vehicle-miles-traveled and prevent congestion increases. The TMP calculates that this would require almost doubling expected revenues, and states, “Even with the additional funding from the 2013 sales tax approval, the ability to make capital investment in the transportation system has clearly fallen short of the amount needed to achieve our transportation goals and objectives . . . . Work prepared for the Blue Ribbon Commission in 2007 shows that with increasing costs for operations and maintenance, these functions could consume the entire transportation budget within a few years. The 2013 sales tax increase for transportation will help delay this event, but without a new long-term and stable revenue source, the ability to invest in enhancements will decline over time.” My translation — unless something radically changes, traffic jams will be permanent.
Stanford University faced a similar situation, but took an innovative “revenue neutral” approach: They combined charges for auto use with incentives for alternatives. Per their transportation planner, in 2000, Stanford wanted to expand their already huge campus, adding 2 million square feet of buildings and 3,000 residential units. Santa Clara County told Stanford to mitigate its traffic impacts by either funding intersection improvements or cutting peak demand. Stanford chose the latter, implementing a transportation demand management program.
They reduced commuter single-occupancy vehicle use from 64.4 percent to 39.3 percent (a 39 percent reduction); peak hour trips were also reduced, even with increased population. Stanford avoided building 3,100+ parking spaces, reportedly saving $107 million, plus it avoided the cost of the intersection improvements. Stanford’s only “stick” was charging for parking — e.g. $300-$800 for an annual parking permit. Its “carrots” included up to a $300 incentive not to drive and free transit passes. New campus development paid $85 per square foot for transportation mitigation measures. All with no “right-sizing”!
Boulder’s inclusionary housing program is supposed to require that residential developers provide 20 percent of their new housing as permanently affordable, but that is not exactly what happens. A large rental development (most residential projects being built are rental) can meet the “20 percent” requirement by paying for the equivalent of one affordable unit off-site for every five on-site. But the developers pay on the basis of 75 percent, not 100 percent, of the actual difference between the market price and the price that would be affordable for someone in the eligible population. To make up for this gap, affordable housing providers use various sources of mostly public money so that more units can be provided than the cash the developers paid would cover. So the developers are getting a deal, the citizens are not getting what they think, and our taxes make up (most of) the difference.
The city’s $9.53 per square foot jobs-housing linkage fee also is rather low. The city calculates the full subsidy required to provide one affordable unit at $186,671. So 20,000 square feet of new office space (potentially well over 100 new employees) barely pays for the subsidy on one unit.
Weeks ago, the council put a 7.5 percent tax on short-term rentals (STRs) on the ballot. Then the city council voted that STRs would become illegal unless the tax passes. But this condition is not in the ballot language. So STR owners might vote no to avoid the tax, not knowing that voting no could completely eliminate their right to do STRs. And voters who don’t like STRs and think that the tax will inhibit STRs might vote yes, not knowing that a no vote might get them what they really want — no STRs at all. (Confusingly, the city website says that “lodging taxes” are 9.5 percent and that STRs are already “unlawful.”)
For all this, the council wants us to raise its pay by $10,000 per member per year just for getting elected, roughly doubling the current pay, plus health benefits.

Popular Posts

Opinion: Opportunity for the new Boulder City Council

Opinion: Is this the end of Boulder as we know it?

Policy Documents: Impact Fees and Adequate Public Facilities